All posts by Richard Drdla

Who Pays?

Who pays for the affordable housing provided under inclusionary zoning is a key question.  The provision does not come free. The requirement for developers to provide housing at less than its full market value creates a cost burden that must be absorbed somehow in the development process.

Knowing who pays this cost burden is fundamental to understanding how IZ works, and also how to create programs that are both effective and as fair as possible to the developers.

The following examination is based upon what has happened with IZ programs in the US. It applies only to mandatory IZ programs, as voluntary (or incentive-based) programs set-up a different dynamic about who shoulders the burden.

The following deals in turn with each of the potential candidates for bearing the cost:
∙   the municipalities;
∙   the developers;
∙   the other homebuyers; and
∙   the landowners.

Municipalities

IZ is not reliant on funding either from the municipalities, or any other level of government, to provide the affordable housing. IZ can and does successfully operate without the use of any financial subsidies.

Having said that, it must be noted funding is used in particular circumstances, and this clearly represents the exception rather than the rule. To be more specific, the funding is always applied on top of what is required by the inclusionary regulations. In this way, the funding is used to reach an even lower level of affordability not possible by IZ alone.

What many municipalities – but no means all – do offer are regulatory concessions in exchange for the affordable housing. These typically allow for relaxing certain regulations (such as, those setting density and height limits, parking standards, and others), waiving fees and charges and using fast-tracked approvals. All of these concessions have an economic benefit, but they do not involve actual cash transfers.

In none of these programs, however, do these concessions make the developers “whole” again. In other words, they are not designed or calibrated to cover the full cost of providing the affordable housing. These concessions might be better seen as political cover, rather than anything close to financial remuneration.

Also, it is important to note there are also successful programs that offer no such concessions whatsoever. This indicates that the provision of the affordable housing under IZ is not dependent upon having these concessions, and so they are really not necessary at all.

There also is a downside to most or all of these concessions, and this in turn raises the question of how appropriate they are. For example, the waiving of fees could lead to a reduction in service levels, or higher fees for others. The use of density bonuses could result in bad planning by permitting higher density where not appropriate. The fast-track approvals for some could cause delays for others.

Finally, municipalities also typically offer cost savings through regulatory concessions of another type. Many allow for the affordable units to be smaller in size, and/or to be built with a lower standard of finish, fixtures or amenity generally. In other words, while the affordable units must still meet an acceptable minimum standard of construction, they need not match the market units in all of their costly aspects. These savings are most unlikely to cover the cost burden, but they do serve to soften that burden.

Developers

IZ programs do not expect nor rely upon the developers absorbing this cost burden. They are particularly not expected to take a loss to their profits. This is an assumption held by many, but one that is wrong.

It is unreasonable to expect developers to take the hit. Although the municipalities under IZ can mandate the provision of affordable housing as a condition of building, they have no power to compel developers to actually build anything. Developers can and will stop building when suffering an undue financial loss caused by the inclusionary requirements.

That the developers are not hit unreasonably by IZ is supported by clear empirical evidence showing that they do not stop production in municipalities with IZ. Two studies, done by non-partisan and university-based organizations (see  Furman and Smart Growth), both independently came to the same conclusion: namely, that IZ has had little or no impact on the overall production of housing in communities where it is used. Where IZ did have an impact – and this should be of no surprise – was on the size and type of housing being produced. In other words, IZ caused the production of smaller units and more multiple housing, but not a cut in the overall housing output.

From these findings, it can be reasonably inferred that developers are able to accommodate to the affordable housing requirements, and to continue to build without significant damage to their bottom lines, at least once these programs are fully established (see FOOTNOTE).

Homebuyers

Developers take the position that under IZ programs they will simply pass on the cost burden to the other buyers in any particular development. In turn, this will inevitably drive up the price of housing generally. As a consequence, these programs are asking the other homebuyers to subsidize the buyers of the affordable units.

The available empirical evidence does not support this position. Specifically, the authoritative studies noted above also examined the impact of IZ on housing prices and came to the same conclusion – namely, that IZ had little or no impact on housing prices. The house prices in municipalities with inclusionary requirements were virtually the same those in municipalities without. And, if there was any rice increase attributable to IZ, it was insignificant when compared with the overall increase in market prices felt in those places.

The reason for this is easy to understand. The price of housing is determined by the market as a whole – in a sort of tug-of-war between all developers and all buyers – and not by the individual developers on their own. Furthermore, developers can be reasonably expected already to be charging what they consider to be the full market value for their product. So, any cost burden imposed by IZ, or any of the myriad other potential cost increases, cannot be simply passed on to the other homebuyers in the form of higher prices.

(Developers sometimes express this position by saying that the homebuyer ultimately pays for everything – including not only the house itself, but also all of the government impositions like development charges, planning fees and inclusionary requirements. This is true but only to a point, because there also is a limit to what the homebuyer will bear and that is expressed through the market price. The job of the developers, if they want to stay in business, is to ensure that all of costs of development (plus their profits) somehow stay within that market price.)

Landowners

Economists that have examined IZ generally conclude the cost burden of these programs is mainly “passed back to the land” (see FOOTNOTE). By this they mean that any additional cost associated with IZ – or at least that not recovered in other ways like the regulatory concessions – results in the developers offering and paying less for the land. This outcome is not specific to IZ; it applies to all cost increases that cannot be included in the overall purchase price.

Before buying any piece of land for development, developers typically do some sort of financial analysis that involves comparing projected revenues with projected costs in one or more potential schemes. The inclusionary requirement is just another one of the many costs that needs to be quantified and considered in this analysis. Ultimately, it is the difference between the revenues and the costs (plus profits) that sets the ceiling for the price they can offer for the land.

Burdening landowners in this way should not be seen as unwarranted or unfair. Landowners in high growth areas especially have benefitted enormously from rising land values that are “unearned’ because they have done nothing to create them. On the other hand, municipalities have had a major role in creating those land values through their infrastructure investments, planning, decisions over land-use and other ways. So, IZ represents a way for municipalities to recover some part of that value that they helped to create but otherwise would fall into private hands.

Summary

The provision of affordable housing under IZ does impose a cost burden that must be absorbed somehow in the development process. That cost burden hits various players in this process in the following ways:

∙ The other homebuyers are not affected by these programs in any substantial way. Specifically, they do not see any significant increase to the house price they pay. While developers will certainly try to pass these costs on to the other homebuyers, their scope for doing this is very limited.

∙ The developers do not, nor are they expected to, absorb this cost. In particular, they do not typically take a profit loss under these programs.

∙ The municipalities generally offer regulatory concessions in these programs, but these concessions only provide limited and partial recompense. They do not offer financial subsidies for meeting the basic inclusionary requirement, but can use subsidies for meeting still deeper levels of affordability.

∙ The landowners must absorb most of the cost burden associated with these programs. Developers typically pass these costs back to the landowners by offering to pay less for the land.

FOOTNOTE

The foregoing analysis describes what happens in mature programs that have been in operation for some reasonable time. In these programs, the market dynamic will have adjusted so that the developers will have learned to limit what they offer for the land. So, in this way the cost burden will be passed back to the purchase price of the land.

There will be a different dynamic when these programs are first introduced. Developers already owning the land, and particularly those that have developments in the approval pipeline, will not be able to pass these costs back to the land. As a consequence, these developers could be hit by the costs of the inclusionary requirements.

To be fair to these developers, this problem will have to be addressed in some way – possibly, by phasing-in the provisions and/or delaying compliance until the adversely effected projects can be flushed through the approval pipeline.

Richard Florida supports inclusionary zoning

Richard Florida, director of the Martin Prosperity Institute at the University of Toronto’s Rotman School of Management, wrote in the Toronto Star on 30 November 2014 an article titled ‘How the new mayor can repair Toronto’.  In that article, while reviewing the most pressing challenges faced by the new mayor, he wrote:

“The first is housing – particularly affordable housing….. The city needs to build new [affordable] housing and lots of it … [through] a concrete strategy. In New York, Bill Blasio introduced a plan for affordable housing that will require developers to include below-market apartments in newly zoned areas. Tory would do well to emulate this kind of public-private partnerships and incent developers … to help pay for more affordable housing.”

This urchin with a complicated name smiles and tell thank you. So buy levitra and send it to the forest. There’s a lot of appreciative. Quiet decide how many send and you can do it.

Home Page

This website is dedicated to promoting the use of inclusionary housing practices in Canada.

It is intended for those wishing to learn generally more about the subject, as well as those looking specifically to develop and implement productive programs.

It consolidates information relevant to Canada on inclusionary practices from a variety of sources and in a variety of ways. Included in its contents are the following:

  • a description of typical inclusionary housing practices (see “How It Works”).
  • a number of case studies of representative inclusionary programs in the US, and their nearest equivalents in Canada (see “Case Studies”).
  • a library of recent and relevant articles from both American and Canadian sources (see “Resources”).
  • a review of the current legislative situation in three provinces of Canada (see “Legislation”).
  • a list of individuals and organizations, mainly from Ontario, that have expressed support for inclusionary housing practices (see “Who’s For It”)
  • an examination of some of central issues raised by the inclusionary practices (see “Issues”).
  • a glossary of many of terms associated with these practices (see “Glossary of Terms”).

This site is meant to be open to the input and contribution of others (see “Contact/Comment/Question”).

What is inclusionary housing?

Inclusionary housing programs are municipal programs that use the development regulations and approval process to oblige private developers to provide a portion of affordable housing within their new market projects.

The policies represent a fundamentally different way to providing affordable housing than the conventional social housing programs used almost exclusively to date in Canada.   Those programs essentially rely on financial subsidies provided by the provincial and/or federal governments. In contrast, inclusionary programs rely solely on the concessions coming out of the regulatory process.

Inclusionary zoning is one particular form of inclusionary housing practices. It is associated with the US, where it was first introduced in the early1970s, and is now used in at least 300 communities, and perhaps over 400, in a dozen or more states.

Inclusionary zoning merits special attention because it has a proven track record in providing affordable housing. It operates under a commonly used set of rules and procedures that have been well-honed after years of experience. These practices in the main could be readily adopted in this country. Even if not fully replicated, that experience offers many lessons that should be heeded here.

There are no equivalent programs in Canada. Some Canadian cities – including Vancouver, Montreal and Toronto – have developed inclusionary programs to support the development of mixed-income communities, but these are more limited in scope and effectiveness than inclusionary zoning as used in the US.

While not all inclusionary housing programs are the same, in order to be effective, they largely adhere to the following key characteristics:

  • engaging private developers to build and provide housing at a below-market price or rent.
  • providing housing that is affordable on a long-term or permanent basis to succeeding owners or renters.
  • providing affordable housing within market housing developments and not on separate sites or in different locations.
  • relying on concessions available through the regulatory process (like density bonuses and fee rebates) – and not financial subsidies – to reduce the cost burden on the developers for providing the affordable housing.
  • operating under fixed and non-negotiable rules that treat all developers in a consistent, equitable and transparent way.

Why inclusionary housing?

There are number of compelling reasons why inclusionary housing practices, and inclusionary zoning specifically, should be used in this country.

  • These practices have been proven to be effective ways in providing affordable housing.

These practices, it is important to stress, do not rely upon government funding to produce affordable housing. They not compete for the scarce dollars upon which conventional programs critically rely. Instead, they represent an alternative and supplementary way of providing affordable housing that adds to the tools available to municipalities.

  • They help to create integrated and mixed-income communities.

 Under these practices, affordable housing will be built virtually everywhere market housing is built. Over time, that means affordable housing will be made available widely across the city, giving people a much wider choice of places to live, including closer to where they work.

  • They  provide for a greater variety and diversity of affordable housing.

The scarce government funding has been focussed – and rightly so – on helping the homeless and others in the greatest need. But, as a consequence, many other affordable housing needs are being overlooked. For example, due to rapidly rising house prices, many moderate-income families can no longer afford to buy new homes in their own communities. Inclusionary practices allow municipalities to meet these and other local needs left unmet by conventional programs.

RD/15Sep2014

This hedgehog with a complicated name smiles and say thank you. So buy levitra and send it to the wood. There’s a lot of appreciative. Quiet decide how many send and you can do it.

Resources

Inclusionary zoning practices in the US have been very widely and extensively studied.  The reports and papers identified on this website are among the many that can be found on the internet, but only include those considered to be most relevant to the Canadian reader.  All in all, they should provide a solid introduction to the key aspects of these practices.

The Canadian research and writing on inclusionary housing practices, on the other hand, is very limited. Furthermore, most of that specifically on inclusionary zoning reflects a shallow understanding of it.   So, only a handful of Canadian documents have been identified here.

Will the inclusionary housing programs stifle the development of market housing?

This question has been carefully researched in the US.  The empirical evidence there conclusively shows that there has been little to no impact on the production of market housing in the municipalities that have adopted inclusionary zoning programs. Continue reading Will the inclusionary housing programs stifle the development of market housing?